Econ Cheat Sheet
Essay by ibenz11 • April 4, 2017 • Study Guide • 1,944 Words (8 Pages) • 1,132 Views
Demand (competitive):Firms/custs=price takers; Prices set by mkt
Consumer Surplus: area below demand and above price line.
[pic 1]
Elastic: |E| > 1 → appr. neg. inf. Inelastic: |E| < 1 → approaches 0
E= -1.1, means: “A 1% incr. in price results in a 1.1% decr in qty”
-Cost paid by custs→Pass through: Es/(Es-Ed) More inelastic cust bears burden
-Income Eof D: %∆QD/%∆QIncome. Cross-P E: %∆QD1 /%∆PD2.
Substitutes: Positive XED Complements: Negative XED
Alusaf Takeaways
- Marginal firm (firm with highest cost relative to others) determines the price of good
- price volatility comes from steep supply or demand
Supply (competitive)
[pic 2]
- MC = ∆Cost/∆Q = ∆VC/∆Q
- Profit max when P = MC(Q*) if firm is operating.
Economic costs: [pic 3]
-AC = TC/Q
-MC = ∆Cost/∆Q = ∆VC/∆Q
-Econ. of Scale: AC ↓with output → MC < AC
-Disecon. of scale: AC ↑ with output → MC > AC
- All costs matter for startup/shut down but only MC matters if operating. If producing, MC matters for decisions that impact output (pricing, ads)
- FC: does not vary with level. of output
- VC: vary with level of output
- Opp. Cost: highest-valued alternative use of an asset
- Sunk Cost: cost spent & cannot be recovered, opp cost = 0
Firms produce as long as MR ≥ MC. AKA, they produce up to the point MR = MC This point can hypothetically be below or above point where MC = AC (i.e., might operate in disecon. of scale) but typically below [right, below]
- Total costs matter for startup/shut down decision, but only MC matters for decisions if operating (ex: pricing, advert.)
Perfect Competition: P=MR in competitive market
IN COMP. MKTS FIRMS FACE A FLAT DEMAND (PERF. ELASTIC) AT THE MARKET PRICE
Total welfare is maximized: P* = MC(Q*) = MWTP(Q*)
Externalities
Activity generates externality when it imposes cost (or benefit) that is not reflected in the price mechanism → produce too much/little
Ex: (-) Factory pollutes river, garbage dump lowers nearby home price. (+) R&D of new ideas; flower farm raises nearby home prices
DWL: Lost surplus due to a distortion from competitive mkts
→when trades occur where the social benefit < social cost & vv
DWL=Tot. Surplus Poss. – ToT. Surplus Achieved (=0 in comp mkts) - Trag. Of Commons = others’ access to the resource impairs everyone’s because of overuse
- Coase theorem = w/ 0 transaction cost, eff. solution occurs regardless of property rights.
- Taxing externalities can increase efficiency.
[pic 4]
Sum of demand and supply: HORIZONTALLY
QTOT = 100 – P when P > 50
QTOT = the sum of the demands when when P < 50
The sum of the demands: we add QUANTITIES (“horizontal sum”)
QD1 = 100 – 2P + QD2 = 100 – P = QTOT = 200 – 3Px
[pic 5]
DWL: Price Ceiling: gov mandates max P. Total loss=B+C. DWL = total loss in welfare. Inelastic D=loss to consumers.
[pic 6]
Similar with price floors (but A is next to B)
Price supports: Gov sets price above the market eq thru purchases of excess S or production restrictions. Consumers lose by paying higher price; producers win; gov has to fund purchases[pic 7]
Tax Subsidies:[pic 8]
Monopoly Power
Firm has market power if faces downward sloping demand curve. In competitive markets firms face flat (perfectly elastic) D curves at market price. Pick Q* such that MR(Q*)=MC(Q*).
P(Q*)>MR(Q*)=MC(Q*). Solve for monopoly price/profit:
1. Find MR (Rev = P*Q, dRev/dQ = MR) → 2. Find MC → 3. Set MR = MC, find Q. For 2 MCs: MR(q1+q2) = MC1(q1)=MC2(q2) → 4. Find P by using Q in original DEMAND function → Calculate profit
-P(Q*) = MC(Q*) for comp. mkt; P > MR, since to increase output, monopolist must lower price for all units. MR has same intercept & 2x slope as inverse demand.
[pic 9][pic 10]
Market Segmentation
[pic 11]
- First degree: extracts all CS for producer
- Second degree: non-linear pricing (eg: different prices/unit for diff quantities of good)
- Third degree: diff groups diff prices
- Mkt Power: firm’s ability to charge markup over MC.
GAME THEORY
Dominant strategy: best course of action regardless of what your opponents do.
In a Nash equilibrium, each player is playing a best response to the actual strategy choices of their rivals. A Nash equilibrium is a stable outcome –no one wants to deviate given what everyone else is doing.
Not always a Nash equilibrium, and sometimes more than one
The Bertrand Model: lowest price firm takes the whole market (split the market if same price).
What is the Nash equilibrium? All at p=c
Even with 2 firms, we get perfect competition outcome.
Unrealistic model: no product differentiation; no uncertainty about demand, no capacity constraints.
How do firms get out of the Bertrand Trap? Matching prices model, Repeated interaction Example: in the following pricing game, the cooperative solution is P1=30 and P2=30. They both continue setting P = 30 as long as the other firm has done so (cooperation phase). If anyone has deviated in the past, start a “price war” in which P = 20 forever after (a Nash reversion “punishment”).
...
...