Essays24.com - Term Papers and Free Essays
Search

Price Elasticity Of Demand

Essay by   •  December 28, 2010  •  1,333 Words (6 Pages)  •  3,075 Views

Essay Preview: Price Elasticity Of Demand

Report this essay
Page 1 of 6

Price elasticity of demand

In economics and business studies, the price elasticity of demand (PED) is an elasticity that measures the nature and degree of the relationship between changes in quantity demanded of a good and changes in its price.

Introduction

When the price of a good falls, the quantity consumers demand of the good typically rises; if it costs less, consumers buy more. Price elasticity of demand measures the responsiveness of a change in quantity demanded for a good or service to a change in price.

Mathematically, the PED is the ratio of the relative (or percent) change in quantity demanded to the relative change in price. For most goods this ratio is negative, but in practice the elasticity is represented as a positive number and the minus sign is understood. For example, if for some good when the price decreases by 10%, the quantity demanded increases by 20%, the PED for that good will be two.

When the Price Elasticity of Demand of a good is greater than one in absolute value, the demand is said to be elastic; it is highly responsive to changes in price. Demands with an elasticity less than one in absolute value are inelastic; the demand is weakly responsive to price changes.

Interpretation of elasticity

Value Meaning

n = 0 Perfectly inelastic.

0 < n < 1 Relatively inelastic.

n = 1 Unit elastic.

1 < n < &#8734; Relatively elastic.

n = &#8734; Perfectly elastic.

For all normal goods and most inferior goods, a price drop results in an increase in the quantity demanded by consumers. The demand for a good is relatively inelastic when the quantity demanded does not change much with the price change. Goods and services for which no substitutes exist are generally inelastic. Demand for an antibiotic, for example, becomes highly inelastic when it alone can kill an infection resistant to all other antibiotics. Rather than die of an infection, patients will generally be willing to pay whatever is necessary to acquire enough of the antibiotic to kill the infection.

Price elasticity of demand is rarely constant throughout the ranges of quantity demanded and price. A good or service can have relatively inelastic demand up to a certain price, above which demand becomes elastic. Even if automobiles, for example, were extremely inexpensive, parking or other related ownership issues would presumably keep most people from owning more than some "maximum" number of automobiles. For these and other reasons, elasticity of demand remains valid only over a specific (and small) range of price. Demand for cars (as well as other goods and services) is not elastic or inelastic for all prices. Elasticity of demand can change dramatically across a range of prices.

Inelastic demand is commonly associated with "necessities," although there are many more reasons a good or service may have inelastic demand other than the fact that consumers may "need" it. Demand for salt, for instance, at its modern levels of supply is highly inelastic not because it is a necessity but because it is such a small part of the household budget. (Technology has increased the supply of salt modernly and reduced its historically high price.) Demand for water, another necessity, is highly inelastic for similar supply side reasons. Demand for other goods, like chocolate, which is not a necessity, can be highly elastic.

Substitution serves as a much more reliable predictor of elasticity of demand than "necessity." For example, few substitutes for oil and gasoline exist, and as such, demand for these goods is relatively inelastic. However, products with a high elasticity usually have many substitutes. For example, potato chips are only one type of snack food out of many others, such as corn chips or crackers, and predictably, consumers have more room to turn to those substitutes if potato chips were to become more expensive.

It may be possible that quantity demanded for a good rises as its price rises, even under conventional economic assumptions of consumer rationality. Two such classes of goods are known as Giffen goods or Veblen goods. Another case is the price inflation during an economic bubble. Consumer perception plays an important role in explaining the demand for products in these categories. A starving musician who offers lessons at a bargain basement rate of $5.00 per hour will continue to starve, but if the musician were to raise the price to $35.00 per hour, consumers may perceive the musician's lessons ability to charge higher prices as an indication of higher quality, thus increasing the quantity of lessons demanded.

Various research methods are used to calculate price elasticity:

* Test markets

* Analysis of historical sales data

* Conjoint analysis

Mathematical definition

The formula used to calculate the coefficient of price elasticity of demand for a given product is

This simple formula has a problem, however. It yields different values for Ed depending on whether Qd and Pd are the original or final values for quantity and price. This formula is usually valid either way as long as you are consistent and choose only original values or

...

...

Download as:   txt (8.1 Kb)   pdf (106.3 Kb)   docx (11.6 Kb)  
Continue for 5 more pages »
Only available on Essays24.com